top of page
Action for Economic Reforms

THE POLITICS OF TRADE POLICY

The author is a consultant to the Department of Agriculture, and a professor in the School of Government of Ateneo de Manila University.


Why do we trade?


Most Filipinos would answer this question with reference to the

benefits of expanded markets for the Philippines’ exports and

consequently more jobs in production for exports.

However, if asked, why do we work? Most would respond that we work to earn money so that we can buy things.


At a personal level, we intuitively know that trading our labor (then

using the money wages as the means of transactions) gives us a higher

standard of living than if we tried to produce everything ourselves. As

individuals, we know and act on the knowledge that specialization

enhances our individual incomes and wealth.


But this knowledge does not seem to hold in our perceptions of the

national economy. We know that a country will be wealthier and have a

better life if the country specializes in producing those products that

it is good at producing, exporting the surplus, and using the proceeds

to buy imports. Yet the notion that the gains from trade should be

measured by what we import, not by what we export, is difficult for

many.


Clearly, many of our leaders and commentators seem to see the benefits

of trade in terms of our ability to increase exports, not in terms of

our ability to increase our imports. For example, Agriculture Secretary

Leonardo Montemayor, along with Trade and Industry Secretary Mar Roxas,

frequently state that it is the national policy and strategy to open up

overseas export markets for the benefit of Philippine farmers.


And it is a common belief among other stakeholders, including farmers

groups, legislators and NGOs that increased imports are actually bad

for the Philippines. Recent media reports on China in the WTO

emphasized concerns that Philippine industries are threatened by

China’s exports. More specifically, there has been official action to

limit Philippine imports of tomato paste on the grounds that such hurt

local tomato paste manufacturers.


Furthermore, most Filipino leaders rail against markets closed to

Philippine exports. But how easy is it for foreign countries to open up

their markets? Our own political debates about protectionism show why

such opening is difficult to achieve.


The Politics of Trade Policy


If all our political leaders were well versed in economic principles,

then they would accept the fact that we export goods to earn foreign

exchange which enables imports. If, in addition to being good

economists, they did not care about being reelected, then they would

adopt the trade policy that would create the most wealth for Filipinos.

The trade policy that would create the most wealth for Filipinos would

be for the Philippines to unilaterally take down all trade barriers.


This action would lower import prices, raise our standard of living and

increase the level of domestic competition. This increased competition

would help keep consumer prices low and lead to increased productivity

as companies invest to stay ahead of domestic and international

competition.


But if unilateral trade liberalization would be so good for us, why haven’t we adopted it?

The answer is simple. Enhancing national wealth is not the goal of

Philippine trade policy. Policy results from the natural desire of our

political leaders to respond to the interests of their constituents.

And whose interests are most likely to be brought to the attention of

our leaders? The interests of those groups for which policy benefits

are large enough to justify advocacy efforts and resources.


In Nueva Ecija, Pangasinan and all other rice-surplus provinces, the

rice farmers and their political leaders have an interest in limiting

rice imports. In Negros and Tarlac, sugar planters and millers have an

interest in limiting sugar imports from Australia to maintain sugar

sector profits and jobs. Countrywide, poultry raisers lobby against the

import of chicken meat.


Clearly, it makes economic sense for these groups to support lobbying

to convince Congress and the administration to adopt protectionist

policies. The sugar industry is the most well organized among all the

commodity-based groups.


There are also groups and NGOs representing producers of coconuts,

coffee, bananas, livestock, poultry, fisheries, mango and cutflowers,

to name some.


Similar forces are at work in every country where competition from Philippine exports threatens their own vested interests.


To see why anti-import forces often win policy debates, consider rice

policy. The large gap between domestic retail and world rice prices

indicates that Filipino consumers would gain about P100 billion per

year if we completely opened our market to rice imports (Estimated as

the gap between world and domestic prices multiplied by the annual

consumption of the population.). In the aggregate, this is a huge sum.

However, on a per capita basis, it amounts to only about P1,250 per

Filipino per year.


In this case, the small gain to each of the many individual Filipinos

would seem to outweigh the losses to the few if we opened our market to

imported rice. Nevertheless, this economic imbalance does not usually

translate into adoption of a free-trade policy because Congress and

policy makers simply do not hear from outraged rice consumers. It only

hears from outraged rice farmers – or their self-appointed

representatives.


The political balance of power in trade policy favors those who

advocate for protectionism. The benefits of protection go to the few

who can organize and lobby for it, whereas the costs of protectionism

are borne by all citizens who do not find it worthwhile to spend time

and money in support of open trade.

{mospagebreak}


What about unfair trade practices?


Of course, companies and industries that lobby for protectionist

policies do not couch their arguments in terms of their desire for

higher profits. Rather, they typically argue their case by blaming

“unfair” competition from foreign exporters.


Often the “unfairness” is caused by lower labor costs in the exporting

countries. But unfair practices can also include government subsidies

to the exporting industries, direct subsidies to exports and

preferential tax treatments. Without some protection, lobbyists argue,

domestic producers would go out of business, and Filipino consumers

would be forced to buy from foreign suppliers.


What should be the response to these arguments?


One response is to simply say, “So what?”

If a company in a foreign country chooses to supply us with a product

at a price lower than we ourselves can make it, then we had better take

advantage of the offer.


If an exporting country’s taxpayers want to subsidize our consumption, then who is taking advantage of whom?


Few countries, with the notable exceptions of Hong Kong, Singapore, and

New Zealand, have adopted this “So what?” response. This is not

surprising given that profits for domestic companies are at risk, and

those at-risk profits can be used to lobby for relief.


If domestic companies or industries go out of business because of

import competition helped by excessive government subsidies, they may

have a legitimate complaint.


Where can harmed industries get relief? From the National Government?

There is a problem with allowing the domestic government to adjudicate

a trade complaint. Past experience suggests that this results in too

much relief and too few imports.


The alternative response is to let a disinterested third party

adjudicate trade complaints beyond domestic boundaries. That third

party is the World Trade Organization (WTO).

Role of the WTO


The WTO was formed upon completion of the Uruguay Round of trade

negotiations in 1994. Its primary purpose is to review trade policies

and to settle trade disputes among member countries. The WTO has no

ability to enforce its findings, so it can settle disputes only if

member countries choose to adhere to WTO rulings.


So far, the track record of adherence to WTO rules is mixed. The EU was

found to be out of compliance when it banned American beef imports

produced with growth hormones. But the ban continues. Other examples

can be cited.


If the WTO finds that a country is out of compliance, then trade

partners are allowed to use sanctions in the form of import tariffs

against the offending country’s exports.


However, is it not odd that a country punishes another country by taxing its own citizens with import tariffs?


For the WTO dispute settlement mechanism to work, countries must

voluntarily give up some of their economic sovereignty and follow WTO

rulings. The benefits to the world trading system from reduced national

sovereignty are obvious: trade volume and value will expand,

accelerating world wealth creation.


Giving up some economic sovereignty is good for each individual country

as well, because WTO rulings can be an effective counterweight against

lobbyists for domestic protectionism. Thus, for example, if Thailand

brings a WTO complaint against Philippine rice tariffs and wins, then

Filipino politicians that have supported the tariffs can say that they

have done all they can do, and Filipinos can enjoy the benefits of less

expensive food.


Future trade policy and agriculture


The best hope for expanded exports of Philippine agricultural exports lies with the WTO.

However, developing country members are protesting that they did not

receive enough of the benefits from the last round of talks. They argue

that they still face unfair competition from EU and US export

subsidies, import tariffs, and producer subsidies.


Developing countries also dislike US production subsidies and import

restrictions on textiles and certain agricultural products such as

peanuts and sugar. Developing countries will need to be convinced that

they will have more time to implement the last agreement, and that any

new agreement will open up developed country markets to their goods.


If the US and the EU are serious about increasing world trade, then a

demonstration of good faith would go far in showing that the new round

of trade negotiations will actually benefit the developing countries.

One demonstration could be a faster timetable by which textile trade is

liberalized. Of course, cotton farmers in the US, India and a few in

the Philippines would line up to fight this liberalization.


In any case, developing countries are looking for a demonstration of

resolve and good faith in favor of open trade from the developed

countries.


Therefore, if the world community wants to move forward with further

trade liberalization, then the US and EU in particular will need to

sacrifice a few sacred cows currently protected from import

competition.

bottom of page