top of page
Action for Economic Reforms

TAXES IN THE COUNTRY MUST BE MADE CERTAIN

The author is the coordinator of the research and policy advocacy group Action for Economic Reforms.


Philippine history informs us that taxation has always been a serious, not to say dangerous, problem.


A chief cause of popular revolts against Spanish colonialism, the

precursor of the Katipunan revolution, was the unjust tax impositions

(i.e., the collection of tribute). In the postcolonial period, various

administrations were irresponsible on matters of taxation—their

foot dragging on tax legislation, their inconsistent and uneven

enforcement of revenue laws, and their reluctance to prosecute big-time tax evaders.


While taxation is indeed an old problem, it likewise has something new.

In the age of globalization, an increasing proportion of economic

activities and transactions transcends national borders. In this

context, developing countries are having a difficult time sustaining

the collection of revenues at a desirable level. The revenue effort

(measured in terms of the amount of taxes collected as a proportion of

the national output) of developing countries, including the more

prosperous ones, has declined in recent years.


Economic homogenization brought about by economic globalization has

eroded the revenues of national governments. The significant reduction

of tariffs—in light of their standardization under the rules of the

World Trade Organization—is one example. This means that governments

have to find other sources of funding to replace the revenues foregone

from much lower tariffs. In the late 1990s, lower tariffs accounted for

about half of the decline of the collection of the Bureau of Customs.

However, locational competition among developing countries prevents

their governments from increasing tax rates. In fact, tax rates are

being lowered in the name of competitiveness and investor confidence.


In other words, taxes have replaced tariffs (in light of their

standardization under the World Trade Organization regime) as a tool of

one country to gain an additional advantage over competitors. The

lowering of tariffs and tax rates, aside from other fiscal incentives

given to investors, has significantly contributed to the fiscal

degradation in many countries.


In the case of the Philippines, the phenomenon of overseas employment

has also led to foregone revenues since overseas Filipino workers

(OFWs) are exempted from paying their income tax in the Philippines.

This is not to say that the income abroad of OFWs should be taxed.

Rather, it illustrates the point that the many facets of economic

globalization—good or bad—pose serious challenges to the national

government in tackling fiscal degradation.


Truth to tell, the revenue problem that we currently face is, in the

main, self-inflicted. Yes, part of the constraint is economic

homogenization and integration. But the Philippine State has enough

instruments to increase tax or revenue effort. The revenue effort in

the Philippines has deteriorated since the late 1990s. In 1997, the

revenue effort was equivalent to 19.4 percent of the Gross Domestic

Product. But in 2000, it dropped to 13.8 percent.


Upon her accession to the presidency, Gloria Macapagal-Arroyo promised

to address the fiscal problem by committing to a policy leading to a

balanced budget. This has not happened. Policy analysts and scholars

will likely agree that the Gloria Macapagal-Arroyo (GMA)

administration’s main failure in regard to the economy is the huge and

serious budget deficit resulting from awfully insufficient revenues.


The International Monetary Fund and even Jose Isidro Camacho, who

recently resigned as the Secretary of Finance, have raised the alarm

over the unsustainable debt and the fiscal crisis.


The intractable budget deficit has terrible consequences for sustaining

Philippine economic growth and fighting poverty. For example, spending

on public construction took a plunge by the third quarter of 2003.

Also, real spending for essential services has been very

tight.


In fairness to the Bureau of Internal Revenue (BIR) and the Bureau of

Customs (BOC), they have performed well in collecting the revenues.

Both revenue collection agencies are expected to meet, if not surpass,

their hard targets for 2003.


In addition, the BIR, which generates more than 70 percent of

government revenues, is putting in place administrative reforms that

strengthen its capacity to efficiently collect taxes. The

administrative reforms cover a wide range of measures: frequent tax

mapping, closer surveillance of hard-to-tax groups, refinement of

implementing rules and regulations, gathering of third-party

information, acceleration of the computerization program, demotion of

inefficient officers and punishment of erring BIR personnel, and

involvement of civil society in the tax campaigns.


In that case, since the BIR and the BOC are doing fine, what accounts for the weak revenues?

The first factor is that despite the administrative reforms that the

revenue collection agencies are pursuing, the tax leakage is so huge

because of infirmities or loopholes in the law, the vagueness of

implementing rules, the lack of information, and the like. An

unpublished paper from the Department of Finance reveals how grave the

tax leakage is. The estimates (for the fiscal year 2001) of the leakage

for various taxes are: a) individual income tax: 72.7 percent; b)

corporate income tax: 39.86 percent; c) minimum corporate income tax:

87.75 percent; and d) value-added tax: 49.94 percent.


The second factor is the weakness in tax policy, not to mention the

lack of political will of the current administration to pass new

revenue laws.


As mentioned earlier, one reason behind the high rate of tax leakage is

compromised legislation. The Comprehensive Tax Reform Package (CTRP),

passed during the Fidel Ramos administration, is a good example of a

piece of legislation that had the best of intentions but was eventually

diluted. One weakness of the CTRP is how to tax the business income of

hard-to-tax groups such as lawyers, doctors, accountants, and other

self-employed professionals. The tax is based on the net income, which

allows many deductible expenses and thus results in massive tax

leakage. There is also inequity in this, for fixed-income earners pay

their taxes using the same tax schedule for individuals with business

income but based on gross income with very limited exemptions. Another

weakness is that the CTRP is still hobbled by the compromises or the

vague rules in relation to the cap on deductible expenses for

corporations and the minimum corporate income tax.


Another example of weak, if not captured, legislation is the excise tax

on cigarettes and alcoholic beverage, the so-called sin products. In

the past, the excise tax was based on factory price, thus an ad valorem

tax. Thus, the manufacturer, to avoid paying a higher tax, would sell

the cigarettes or the beer at a lower price to an affiliated

distributor (a dummy). To curb such practice, the government shifted

from ad valorem to specific. It sounds good, except for the fact that

the enacted specific tax is not indexed to inflation. Over the years,

then, the amount of excise tax collected by the government from the sin

products has deteriorated in real terms.

{mospagebreak}


The GMA administration promised to rectify the weakness by introducing

a law that will index the specific tax. But nothing has happened; the

bill languishes in a committee in the Lower House. In a word, do not

expect any new taxes to be passed in an election year.


The GMA administration has done nothing, either, to rationalize the

fiscal incentives. These incentives—in the form of tax exemption, tax

credits, and subsidies—have a huge opportunity cost. It is estimated

that in 2000, the foregone revenues from the incentives amounted to

PhP38.9 billion. Yet the wisdom of offering generous incentives to

investors is questionable. The critics, including the International

Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World Bank (WB), have argued that fiscal

incentives are not a decisive factor in attracting investments.


Investors are more sensitive to policy predictability, low level of

corruption, peace and order, good infrastructure, and a robust internal

market.


We can no longer afford to wait for tax reforms to be implemented. We

can only hope that whoever holds power in the next administration will

use the “honeymoon” period with the public to immediately carry out

reforms in tax policy and tax administration.


The tax reforms should be guided by the following principles: a) a

progressive and equitable system of taxation, b) a buoyant tax system

to keep revenues flowing to sustain development programs, and c) an

efficient tax system that increases the tax base and plugs the

loopholes to minimize tax evasion and avoidance.


It is always desirable to have a progressive tax system. Unfortunately,

global competition has pressured nation-states to sacrifice

progressivity in favor of tax rates and a tax system that are generous

to capital and internationally mobile, highly skilled labor. Direct

taxes

(on income, capital, and other assets) are invariably associated with a

progressive system of taxation. Government must come to grips with this

question: Up to what extent can the national government promote direct

taxation, without incurring greater costs that result from the failure

to attract capital and technology or even from the departure of its own mobile factors of production?


At the same time, indirect taxes can be designed to be less regressive

and even to enhance progressivity. For example, government can

introduce higher excise taxes on luxurious or affluent consumption and

on socially undesirable goods (e.g., tobacco and liquor).


We have pointed out some key elements that can form the nucleus of the

tax reform agenda of the next administration. To reiterate:


  • Carry on the tax administration reforms that the present BIR and BOC are doing

  • Address the infirmities of the Comprehensive Tax Reform Package.

  • Legislate the indexation to inflation of the specific tax on sin products.

  • Rationalize the fiscal incentives given to investments.

  • Introduce progressive, efficient, and equitable taxes (taxes on pollution, on affluent consumption, and other activities that have negative externalities).


On the international front, the Philippine government should have a

keen interest in the shaping of global rules in relation to financing

and taxation. Among other things, the government should support rules

that will: a) put in place mechanisms and arrangements for coordination

and harmonization where appropriate and necessary, b) prevent

locational competition from becoming a race to the bottom, and c) give

room to nation-states to exercise flexibility and autonomy amidst

economic homogenization.


The specific design of the reform agenda is very important. Already,

the IMF is recommending that government increase the rate of the

value-added tax, which is certainly controversial. The measures we have

enumerated above, if carried out, will not warrant a move to increase

the rate of a highly regressive tax.


Let us, then, keep in mind the wise words of the eminent Gunnar Myrdal

(in Political Element in the Development of Economic Theory): “Taxation

is a most flexible and effective but also a dangerous instrument of

social reform. One has to know precisely what one is doing lest the

results diverge greatly from one’s intentions.”

bottom of page