top of page
Action for Economic Reforms

O CARTEL!

The author is research associate of the Philippine Institute for Development Studies PIDS (on-leave).


For over a decade from the 1970s to the 1980s, the Philippine cement

industry thrived under a powerful, government-sanctioned cartel that

captured Filipino consumers and industry users including the

government. In the absence of information, the government, through the

Philippine Cement Industry Authority (PCIA), had to coordinate closely

with the industry association, the Philippine Cement Corp.

(Philcemcor). This led to the collusion of firms through informal

agreements to set production quotas and geographic markets. By

regulating prices and outputs, prices were no longer the product of

competition among rival producers but more of the outcome of

negotiations between the government and a small number of producers.


During the 1990s, the PCIA was abolished, restrictions on cement

imports were removed, prices were deregulated, and tariffs were

gradually reduced from 50% in 1979 to the current level of 5%. But

despite these liberalization and deregulation episodes, no effective

competition has emerged. Implicit coordination in the industry has

continued because of the firms’ market power. Their collusive behavior

has become more glaring as prices rose substantially and continuously

in a simultaneous manner since 1999, a time characterized by excess

supply, overcapacity, and weak demand. Ironically, this parallel

behavior also coincided with tariff reduction and entry of imports and

new foreign players in the industry.


Price-cost margins, indicators used to measure market power, were high

at 42%, higher than the average margin for the whole manufacturing

industry. A firm with market power is able to charge price

significantly above cost while a firm without market power would charge

a price closer to cost. The industry’s market power is attributed to

the following factors: high and stable market shares and high

concentration levels in the last 13 years, difficulty of entry owing to

the large capital requirements of cement manufacturing, limited import

competition due to the natural characteristics of cement – high

transportation and handling costs and short shelf-life, inelastic

demand which provides power to firms to control prices, and absence of

competition policy in the country.


Cement average ex-plant prices indicate that there is not much price

variation in the industry. In February 2000, the average price in

Northern Luzon was P101/bag, 99.17/bag in NCR, and P100/bag in

Mindanao. The standard deviation, a measure of price variability, was

also low. It was 1.15 in Northern Luzon, 1.04 in NCR, and 1.1 in

Mindanao.


Under a competitive environment, this low variation in price would

imply that firms would have more or less similar cost structure.

Otherwise, the only logical explanation for the low price variation

would be the presence of price coordination among firms. Cement

financial data indicate that their production costs vary extensively.

In 1999, average production cost per bag (in pesos) were as follows:

Bacnotan 87.50, Northern 58.50, Solid and FR 76, Titan 127, Rizal 194,

Fortune 75, Davao Union 79, Apo Cement 98.60, and Grand 63.70.


With these different cost structures and assuming competitive

conditions, the firms should be quoting different prices. If

competition is effective, inefficient firms are weeded out allowing the

market shares of efficient firms to increase. Obviously, their cost

structure cannot explain the low variation in prices that we observe.


Low-cost firms share the market with high-cost firms. What is

preventing efficient firms from undercutting their inefficient rivals

in the market? Cement is a homogeneous good and since government

policies that may distort market prices are already abolished, the only

logical explanation is the presence of price coordination and the

threat of a price war which sustains cartel activities.


Aside from price uniformity, another characteristic of cartel prices is

stability for long periods of time and occasional episodes of

volatility for short periods which indicates cheating. Between 1993 to

1996, price movements showed a fairly stable movement, prices rose

during the dry season and fell during the rainy months. When the 1997

Asian crisis struck, big drops in prices were registered starting in

mid-1997 which eventually led to a price war. Note that competitive

firms react to a negative demand shock by reducing output, in contrast,

a cartel reacts by expanding output or engaging in a price war. After

hitting a price of P45/bag in December 1998, the lowest level hit

during the price war period, prices began to increase in a simultaneous

fashion beginning in January 1999. In May 2000, price/bag was already

P110; in mid-2001, it was around 140-145 per bag.


The outcome of cartel behavior is against public interest and is highly

distortive of economic efficiency. Cartels limit competition and allow

firms to manipulate prices to the detriment of consumers, other

industry users including the government. The recent Department of Trade

and Industry ruling of protecting the industry through increased

tariffs tends to show that the government remains captured by the

industry it is supposed to regulate. It is no wonder that cartel

behavior persists in the country; the government allows it through its

use of regulatory measures, through its failure to legislate the

correct laws against anti-competitive behavior; and simply ignoring

that such behavior exists.


Given our weak institutions, firms can successfully organize to

influence government policy. Rather than compete, firms will always

lobby for government protection and hide from the challenges of market

competition by invoking antidumping and safeguard measures or engaging

in cartel activities. The cement case illustrates that our previous

experience of regulation, promotion, and protection encouraged greater

concentration, limited the potential for competition, and prevented the

development of a culture of competition in the country.


The Tariff Commission must exercise caution in imposing safeguard

measures to the industry given the firms’ market power and tendency to

collude. These measures could easily become protectionist tools, hence,

the Commission must carefully weigh the welfare gains and losses of

increasing tariffs to the industry. It is only with competition that

consumers will obtain the best possible goods at the lowest possible

prices. Cartels are not the key to the survival of domestic industries,

effective competition is.


(This article is based on a study by the author entitled “The State of Competition in the Philippine Manufacturing Industry.”)

bottom of page