top of page
  • Action for Economic Reforms

FROM LAZY LIBERALIZATION TO LAZY PROTECTIONISM

This piece is critique of the President's recent pronouncements to slow

down tariff reduction schedules. It is argued in this piece that by

merely focusing trade policy, be it liberal or protectionist, the

government fails to address the roots of Philippine industrial atrophy.


The author is Trade and Industrial Policy Analyst of Action for

Economic Reforms, and Instructor at the Department of Economics, School

of Social Sciences, Ateneo de Manila University.


That unbridled globalization is no longer in vogue is not news to many

people. The swift opening up of domestic markets to foreign competition

has failed to deliver what it once loftily promised… economic growth,

prosperity, and development. In truth, the current brand of

globalization has only served to highlight inequalities within and

among nations, and has only exacerbated economic vulnerabilities and

social cleavages that continue to threaten societies and nations today.


However, to hear President Macapagal – Arroyo declare that she too has

come to realize this fact is definitely news. A strong proponent of

liberalization programs in the 1990s, the President's recent

declaration to slow down the reduction of tariffs "to encourage the

manufacturing sector and signal industrial policy" sent market

fundamentalists into cardiac arrest, made disciples out of industry

leaders, and left most progressive thinkers bemused, if not downright

skeptical. Is this an honest-to-goodness shift in policy framework, or

is it simply a signal of the administration's kowtow to pressure or

particularistic interests?


The President's pronouncements are without a doubt a spark of hope for

many of our industries. In the absence of supporting measures to ensure

business viability and transformation, liberalization has led many

local industries to atrophy, and in the face of competitor countries

like China, India and Vietnam, has made each of us witness to the

erosion of our competitive advantage in cheap labor. One has to ask,

however, whether protection in the form of slower tariff reductions, in

and by itself, will be enough to guarantee revitalized industries and

better quality jobs.


The fact of the matter is that liberalization and protection are but

two sides of the same coin. Each has its own claims to industrial

promotion, the former promising more efficient production and resource

allocation, the latter ensuring better and less risky profit incentives

for business. Each too has its own downsides: liberalization may lead

to destruction of presently inefficient industries and job loss, while

protection nurses these inefficiencies and allows them to persist. Both

suggest a certain attitude towards the free market: openness or

distrust.


The foremost truth that binds the two, however, is that neither is

sufficient to promote the growth and development of industry. The

clearest and most resonating lesson of the East Asian Miracle is that

coherence and completeness of a country's industrial promotion

strategy, which definitely includes but should not be limited to trade

policy, are of primary importance.


Not all industries that are presently uncompetitive are inherently

uncompetitive in the longer term if they are given the time and

resources to develop new skills and master new technologies. An equally

crucial point to emphasize, however, is that there are certainly some

inherently uncompetitive activities that deserve to be closed down

immediately, and some that can be exposed immediately to international

markets. In between lies the bulk of manufacturing industry, which has

to undergo a process, varying in duration and content by activity, of

"relearning" and new capability acquisition, after which it can cope

with import competition and establish a position in export markets.


Therefore, rather than taking liberalization alone or protection alone,

the strategy should be to customize industrial policy according to the

specificities of each industry, guided by a realistic assessment of

their competitiveness potential and a clear evaluation of which are

viable in the medium term and which are better left to disappear in

view of the costs involved. In short, the best way to approach

industrial strategy is still to gear it directly to enhancing

industrial competitiveness.


Given however that industries have varying levels of competitiveness

potential, and that resources and skills in the government and the

economy at large are very limited, it is best to adopt a targeted and

selective approach. As targeting and selectivity require huge amounts

of information, this strategy should clearly be developed after a close

study of and in collaboration with the industrial sector. This

admittedly involves some degree of inspired guess-work, but even the

Nobel Laureate Joseph Stiglitz asserts that making mistakes is better

than not taking risks. Such should perhaps NEDA Director General Neri's

top priority. Moreover, the programme should be pre-announced so that

enterprises have time to adjust, and once announced, government should

stick to it to ensure its credibility. Government must not consent to

backsliding that allows inefficient performers to survive indefinitely

and that creates room for rent-seeking activities and corruption.


However, an important caveat as well is that all interventions have to

be designed flexibly and monitored constantly so that mistakes can be

rectified as they become apparent. There are good examples in the

private sector on how to do this, but perhaps the most effective check

is to impose performance requirements (e.g. export growth) and to make

officials more directly accountable. Finally, and perhaps most

importantly, such a programme must be situated within a broader,

long-term national development framework that is cognizant of socially

sensitive and essential industries that, regardless of competitiveness

and efficiency considerations, deserve to be protected and nurtured.


Moreover, in light of the hostile stance of the global market towards

selective interventions, a sincere effort at industrial promotion must

also include the pursuit of more proactive and aggressive negotiation

position in bilateral and multilateral trade agreements. This would

mean, in the immediate term, closely watching and actively

participating in the discussions running up to and during the Cancun

Ministerial of the World Trade Organization.


Unfortunately, there is little evidence that the President is willing

to play a more activist role in industrial promotion beyond simply

sticking to bare minimums. In the same speech where she made her bold

declarations against unbridled globalization, she too said,

"Officials… are the last people who should second-guess a business

activity. At most, they should monitor businesses for the harm they

might do the community. But that is all. … Let the market separate the

good from the bad."


At the end of the day, while tariff barriers may offer some protection

to domestic industries, their fate still largely relies on the market…

the same market that recognizes no potential, knows no time dimension,

nor admits any of its failures in reality. It seems that the

President's therapy for the havoc that lazy liberalization wreaked on

Philippine industries is nothing but lazy protectionism. For in the

absence of a clear and comprehensive strategy of harnessing the

potentials of Philippine industry, lazy protectionism is better than

lazy liberalization in one and only one way… It paves the way for

industries to lobby government officials for their own particularistic

interests, fattening the pockets of those who wield the power to

protect.

Comments


bottom of page