top of page
  • Action for Economic Reforms

CORRUPTION AND INVESTMENT

The author is the Coordinator of Action for Economic Reforms, a research and policy advocacy NGO focusing on macroeconomic policy and governance issues.


The perception that corruption under the Gloria Macapagal Arroyo (GMA) administration is rampant sticks.


Some serious charges exposed by the so-called Magdalo group in

connection with unabated corruption in the Armed Forces of the

Philippines and Panfilo Lacson’s startling accusations against “Jose

Pidal” are the latest dramatic examples.


The fact that even those who condemn the Magdalo group for

participating in the failed coup d’etat acknowledge the legitimacy of

its grievances suggests how deep-seated corruption is. As for the Pidal

expose, the public attitude is to shoot the messenger but not the

message.


Even before these issues exploded, serious charges of corruption had

already besieged the GMA administration – for example, the alleged

anomalies relating to the construction of the Diosdado Macapagal

highway and the building of the new international airport.


Stories also circulate about investors giving bribes amounting to

hundreds of millions of pesos for changes in the rules, or for

defensive lobbying to ensure that rules are not reversed, or simply for

business entry. The problem though is no one is willing to do a Chavit

Singson act and file formal complaints in the proper venue.


Of course, corruption has long been a trademark of Philippine political

and economic life. Joseph Estrada fell because of the blatant

corruption under his administration. Charges of high-level corruption

tainted the Fidel Ramos administration, the more prominent being the

Amari and the Philippine Centennial deals. Corazon Aquino is saintly,

but many believe that “Kamag-anak, Inc.” took advantage of her

administration to gain privileges. Undeniably, the most brazen

corruption and cronyism occurred during the Marcos dictatorship though

some would argue that the Estrada administration’s venality was not far

behind. Before the Marcos period, corruption was a main cause of the

electoral defeats of incumbents.


In this light, people across the spectrum – progressives and

conservatives, liberals and fascists, etc. – regard corruption as the

country’s central problem. The conventional wisdom is that corruption

impairs investments and growth. Corruption increases the costs of doing

business. Corruption results in output that is inferior or substandard

(as the briber has to reallocate funds for the bribe and hence scrimp

on production).


It undermines merit-based criteria, as contracts are awarded to cronies

or favored parties (contrary to the view that the most efficient entity

has the capacity to shell out the highest bribe and hence has the best

chance to win).


Corruption, too, creates negative externalities. A number of empirical and econometric studies support the conventional view.


Widely cited is Paolo Mauro’s “Corruption and Growth” (1995) that shows

the negative association of corruption with high investments.


Nevertheless, the conventional wisdom has repeatedly been challenged.


Following Samuel Huntington (1968), some scholars have argued that

corruption is a “grease” that speeds up the process of investment

transactions. In addition, the supporters of the theory of the “second

best” are pragmatic to concede that some corrupt activities can negate

distortions in policy. For example, smuggling, in a situation of very

high tariffs, provides producers with lower-priced imported inputs and

consumers with cheaper consumption goods.


Many are likewise puzzled by the experience of high growth in East Asia

despite widespread corruption and rent seeking. How can one explain the

rapid growth over a long period in China or in Suharto’s Indonesia in

spite of the high degree of corruption in these countries?


In this light, the volume edited by J. Edgardo Campos (The Boom and

Bust of East Asia, 2001) offers penetrating insights. Mr. Campos’s

thesis, proven by regression results, is that high levels of corruption

do not deter investments and growth, as long as such corruption is

predictable. (That is, those who bribe are certain or likely to get the

government favors or contracts.)


This predictability through systematic and organized corruption

explains the phenomenon in China, Indonesia, Malaysia, Thailand, and

South Korea.


The worst situation is that of high levels of corruption together with

unpredictability in the outcomes arising from corruption. This

unfortunately is the Philippine case. To quote Campos: “Corruption

regimes that are more predictable… have less negative impact on

investment than those that are less predictable.”


Indeed, the ideal situation is to have low levels of corruption

combined with policy predictability or certainty. But the difficult

question for developing countries is how to get there.


The contributors to the Campos volume present country studies that show

how transitional institutional frameworks and governance arrangements –

definitely far from ideal in securing property rights or enforcing

contracts since they still accommodate corruption and rent seeking –

can suffice to sustain high investments


In China’s case, Shuhe Li and Peng Lian explain how the mechanisms of

local information, interregional competition, and “market-preserving

authoritarianism” contribute to the flow of investments and the

enforcement of contracts and property rights.


In the case of Indonesia during the Suharto regime, Andrew MacIntyre

argues that while the dictator gained tremendously from corruption,

Suharto was wise enough to put institutional constraints on corruption

so as not to kill the goose that lays the golden eggs.


Suharto minimized the costs through the surveillance of officials and

the identification of sectors not to be affected by corruption.


Moreover, he agreed to have some measures that tied government’s own

hands, to give a credible commitment to investors in the event of

uncertainty. An example of this was the liberalization of the capital

account, which proved to be disastrous in light of the massive capital

flight in 1997-1998.


To be sure, the lessons and experiences from the East Asian countries

in managing sustained growth in conjunction with corruption are not

transferable to the Philippines. For one thing, some neighboring

countries have (or had) authoritarian regimes that perform the role of

monopoly suppliers, thus minimizing gridlock and reducing the

possibility of veto. However, Philippine society has shown its

preference for democracy in choosing leaders, policies, and rules. The

Marcos dictatorship was a failure, for among other things, it lacked

legitimacy and hence failed to build a social and political consensus

that was a necessary condition for sustained growth.


Yet, it is fairly clear that the present setup is insufficient to

manage corruption and thus make it more predictable. Emmanuel S. de

Dios and Hadi Salehi Esfahani offer an institutionalist framework to

address this problem. Concretely, they propose the reduction of

presidential power by devolving such power to the other branches of the

National Government and to the local governments, by increasing the

bureaucracy’s autonomy, and by binding government to global commitments.


Not everyone will agree to these proposals. But what alternatives can

the Philippines offer, in light of its own experience with corruption?

Thus far, the stereotyped approach of moral and punitive means has not

worked. Perhaps it is time to acknowledge an approach that “reforms”

corruption, which an institutionalist framework can better address.

Comments


bottom of page